Tuesday, March 5, 2019
World Trade Orgtanization and the Ready Made Garment Industry of Bangladesh; a Critical Analysis
Assignment On WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION AND THE made GARMENT perseverance OF BANGLADESH A CRITICAL ANALYSIS Submitted To prof Dr. Khondoker Bazlul Hoque surgical incision of creative activity-wide Business University of Dhaka. Submitted By Sheikh Rashedul Islam Student ID 80116043 Subject speculation & Practice of International Business Course NoEIB-510 MBA (Evening Program), Department of International Business University of Dhaka. Submission Date January 6, 2012 ACKNOWLEDGEMENT I am warmly thankful to the stemma teacher of Theory & Practice of International Business, Professor Dr.Khondoker Bazlul Hoque whose encouragement, guidance and corroboration from the initial stage to the final level enabled me to stimulate an at a visit placestanding of the topic and prep ar this assignment. I thank each of those who back up me in any respect during the completion of the assignment. DateJanuary 6, 2012 knock back of table of contents Abstract4 Introduction5 Textile conditional relations vs exportingationations in Bangladesh6 info & Simulations7 aggregation of GTAP database version 5_19 Ready made garments MFA export evaluate analogous9 Average signification-weighed duty in Bangladesh 11 RESULTS 12Experiment 1 ABOLITION OF MFA QUOTAS13 Conclusion17 Reference18 WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION AND THE READYMADE GARMENT INDUSTRY OF BANGLADESH A CRITICAL ANALYSIS ABSTRACT Since the 1980s the export oriented readymade garment (RMG) industry of Bangladesh has undergo an extraordinary evolution This trend was accompany by a terrific rise in the export shell out from 0. 2% in 1980 to nearly 75% in 1997-98. High stringency on low grade-added products, strong dependence on imported cloths and blue regional concentration of exports characterize Bangladeshs RMG sector.The principal(prenominal) policy example is given by the WTOs Agreement on Textiles and Clothing (ATC) which follows the condition Multifibre Arrangement (MFA). By 2005, the sector is to be seriousy integrated into GATT rules and alive quotas currently hampering championship get out come to an end. Thus, it evoke be pass judgment that worldwide trade in framework and garment will turn out and that return in flat discriminated regions will emergence. However, lively import obligations for frameworks, strongly supported by local textile producers, hinder the current RMG mathematical product in Bangladesh.In this paper we will discuss how prox policy developments may affect the RMG sector of Bangladesh. For the synopsis we used the comparative noneffervescent general equilibrium puzzle GTAP. In this model quotas importing from the MFA musical arrangement atomic number 18 included as export tax equivalents. Comp bed to china and India, Bangladesh has less curtail access to the most important markets the EU and regular army. The experiments simulate a full descriptor-out of the MFA quotas, as thoroughly as a reduction of import tariffs in the textile and clothing sector.First conclusions indicate an increase in RMG occupation in Bangladesh, notwithstanding comp atomic number 18d to chinaware and particularly India growth rates are sooner modest. It is shown that the make resulting from textiles imports tariff reduction in Bangladesh itself are stronger than the MFA grade out. This demonstrates the importance of the existing tariff regime for textiles. Further to a greater extent than than than it support be shown that RMG imports from Bangladesh to NAFTA are reduced while China and peculiarly India signifi flocktly expands their exports to this region.Although Bangladesh stooge augment its RMG exports on the second monumental market, the EU, again it looses in engagement against China and India. INTRODUCTION The export oriented readymade garment (RMG) industry of Bangladesh has experienced an extraordinary evolution having started with 9 enterprises in the late seventies, the number has now grown to e veryplace 3000. This trend was accompanied by a tremendous rise in the export carry on from 0. 2% in 1980 to over 80% in 1998 (WTO, 2002 and figure 1). With a cheer of well-nigh 4 billion US$, the RMG industry has clearly become the dominant mention for Bangladeshs export earnings.Figure 1 Textile imports and RMG exports of Bangladesh Source GTAP v5_1. However, Bangladeshs RMG sector is characterized by some unfavourable circumstances the sector super depends on imported fabrics. In 115 out of 127 categories of fabrics the share of imports exceeds 70% (CPD, 1999). Figure 1 shows that over the years about half the export earnings were spent on textile imports. Since natural conditions in Bangladesh just every last(predicate)ow for a huge expansion of cotton production, this problem will continue in the future. Additionally, the added value in the apparel sector is quite low.The sourcing of textiles for the Bangladesh RMG industry has diversityd dramatically over the last 20 yea rs, as can be seen from figure 2. In the 1980s, the dominant suppliers were the high-income Asian countries, led by Japan with an import share of more than 40%, and followed by Korea with a share of about 10%. Until the mid 1990s, Korea had taken over the present of Japan as the leading source for textile imports, with a share of around 30%. Since then, India has expanded its textile imports into Bangladesh, and more recently China has started to assume an increasing importance.By 1998, 35% of textile imports were sourced from China and about 20% from India. Figure 2 Composition of textile imports of Bangladesh pic Source GTAP v5_1. abide by Last figures for India are 1997 data. Figure 3 Bangladesh exports of clothing to USA and EU 1980-1998 (in billion US$) pic Source GTAP v5_1. Bangladeshs RMG sector is concentrated twain in regards to export products and export markets the concentration of products is much high than for India and China, cardinal important competitors on pla netary markets, while 90% of Bangladesh RMG exports are qualifying to two markets, the EU and the USA (see figure 3).The chief(prenominal) policy role model is given by the WTOs Agreement on Textiles and Clothing (ATC) which follows the fountain Multifibre Arrangement (MFA). By 2005, the sector is to be fully integrated into GATT rules and existing quotas currently hampering trade will come to an end. Bangladesh confronts quota in two markets, the USA and Canada. Due to the Generalised System of Preference (GPS) the important EU market provides no quota restrictions for Bangladeshs textile and clothing products. With respect to some early(a) competitors on this market like India and Sri Lanka this presents a comparative advantage.Nevertheless, some restrictions resulting from the Rules of Origin overly apply for imports from Bangladesh. In the near future, the EU market for textile and clothing will not exclusively be affected by changes in the ATC agreement, hardly by bila teral agreements connected to foster enlargement processes of the EU as well as developments with regard to the EU? s item regional preferences. This will particularly influence the market access of the primordial and east europiuman countries and Turkey. In general, the abolishment of textiles and clothing quotas will jump an expanded worldwide trade and production in now discriminated regions.This of course will lead to country specific do depending on regional idiosyncrasies. Concerning Bangladesh existing import tariffs for textiles, strongly supported by local textile producers, hinder the current RMG production in Bangladesh. In the recent onetime(prenominal) the pure existence as well as the rate of these tariffs has been under heavy discussion in Bangladesh (e. g. The Independent, 2002). Therefore, we will discuss how different future policy developments may affect the RMG sector of Bangladesh.This includes the changes in the spherical ATC agreement, advertise dev elopments on the huge import market EU as well as changes in the national tariff regime of Bangladesh. DATA and SIMULATIONS The analysis was done using the comparative static general equilibrium model GTAP. Since the GTAP framework is well known and documented (see Hertel, 1997 and http//www. gtap. agecon. pur overdue. edu), we will not refine on its theoretical back screen background here. However, it is important to note that import barriers resulting from the ATC agreement are calculated into tariff equivalents (see Francois & Spinanger, 2002 and table 2).For the experiments the GTAP database version 5. 1 was used, which contains 66 countries and 57 sectors. The selected aggregation can be obtained from 1. Table 1 Aggregation of GTAP database version 5_1 Regions Sectors Bangladesh Rice paddy rice, processed rice China other(a) Grains wheat, cereal grains (incl.HongKong) Fibres plant-based fibres India OthCrop oilseeds, sugar crops, other crops, vegetables, fruits and nut s High-income Asia (HincAsia) Ofood raw milk, cattle, sheep, goats & horses, other animal products, vegetable oils and fats, Other Asia (OthAsia) dairy products, bovine cattle, sheep & goat meat products, other meat products, wool, silk-worm USA cocoons, beverages and tobacco products, food products Canada (CAN) Extract fishing, forestry, coal, oil, minerals, gas Mexico & primordial the States Tex textiles (CentrAm) Wap vesture apparel atomic number 63an Union (EU) Lea trounce products Turkey LabintMan motor vehicles & parts, chemicals, wood products, paper products, publishing, Central and Eastern atomic number 63 petroleum, coal products, mineral roducts, metals, metal products, (CEEC) CapIntMan transport equipment, electronic equipment, machinery & equipment, ferrous metals, other Rest of the World (ROW) manufactures Svces electricity, construction, gas manufacture, trade, transport, distri simplyion, water, communication, financial services, insurance, bus iness recreational services, creation administration & defence, education, health, dwellings If exports are constrained under the MFA export quota regime, there are begin exports and higher charges than in a free-trade situation. The effects of this constraint can be measured in terms of an implicit export tax or tariff equivalent of the quota rent. Table 2 presents such estimates (from the GTAP v5_1 database) for the wearing apparel industry. 1 The table indicates that the Multi-Fibre-Agreement for wearing apparel is less restrictive for Bangladesh than it is for its main competitors China and India. Table 2 Ready made garments MFA export tax equivalent (million US$, 1997 and as % of interior(prenominal) market value of exporting region)* ( from ( to USA Canada EU All Total other countries Bangladesh 103 5 80 2 190 9% 9% 8% 5% 8% China (incl. HongKong) 1974 166 848 72 3059 31% 34% 14% 2% 10% India 460 46 290 12 807 52% 52% 18% 2% 24% High-income Asia 68 4 2 0 74 2% 2% 0% 0% 1% Other Asia 563 29 281 8 880 10% 10% 7% 1% 7% Mexico & Central the States 277 3 7 0 287 3% 4% 5% 0% 3% Turkey 24 1 0 0 25 5% 5% 0% 0% 1% Central and Eastern Europe 12 1 0 0 13 5% 5% 0% 0% 0% All other countries 83 3 34 1 121 2% 3% 0% 0% 1% Total 3563 257 1542 94 5457 Source GTAP v5_1. * Not all countries are set about quotas on each export market.The tariff equivalents described here result from the estimation of rents and thus include not only direct unless similarly indirect effects originating from the ATC agreement. The estimated value of the export tax equivalent for Bangladesh is 190 million US$ in 1997, which amounts to 8% of the domestic value of total RMG exports. Exports to the North the Statesn markets from China and India apparently face higher quota restrictions, as the estimated ad-valorem tariff equivalent of the quota shows. For example, Indian exports to the USA would be more than 50% cheaper without the quota. The current RMG production in Bangladesh is affected not only by export measures but also by existing import tariffs. Although the country has xperienced some liberalization in the recent past, tariffs for intermediate inputs and especially textiles are high compared to other products entering Bangladesh (see table 3). In international comparison Bangladesh levies congenerly high import taxes on its textile imports (table 4). Tariffs of more than 30% of the import value are not uncommon. On (trade-weighted) average, textile imports into Bangladesh face a tariff equivalent of 29%, which is three propagation as high as the world average. According to the GTAP database, the tariffs on textiles restrain contributed approximately 420 million US$ to tax revenues in Bangladesh. Table 3 Average import-weighed tariff in Bangladesh, fiscal year 1991-99 Import categories 1991 1995 1999 mean(a) inputs 24. 1 26. 3 21. 5 Capital goods 18. 7 12. 5 8. 57 Final consumer goods 47. 3 26. 4 11. 2 All imports 2 4. 1 20. 8 14. 68 Source WTO (2002) after NBR. Table 4 Ad valorem tariff equivalent for textiles (in %) ( from ( to Bangladesh Average all import destinations Bangladesh n. a. 11 China (incl.HongKong) 36 12 India 10 10 High-income Asia 33 18 Other Asia 20 11 USA 32 8 Canada n. a. 2 Mexico & Central America n. a. 8 European Union 32 5 Turkey n. a. 12 Central and Eastern Europe n. a. 10 Rest of the World 34 10 Total 29 10 NoteCalculated from value of imports at domestic market costs over value of imports c. i. f. , GTAP v. 5_1. n. a. not procurable or import flow negligible.Since the RMG sector of Bangladesh is restricted on the export stance as well as on the imports the simulations analyzed in this paper include two experiments. Experiment 1 (EXP 1) focuses on the export market. It simulates firstly a complete phase-out of the ATC agreement and secondly specific applicable developments on the EU market such as the Eastern exaggeration and a preferential agreement with Turkey. Experiment 2 (EXP 2) additionally describes a reduction of import tariffs in the textile sector of Bangladesh by 20%. RESULTS Experiment 1 ABOLITION OF MFA QUOTAS What can be expected for Bangladesh if all quota restrictions on textiles and garments trade are abolished by December 31st, 2004, as foreseen in the ATC?The main competitors of Bangladeshs RMG sector, located in India and China, are relatively more restricted by the ATC agreement than Bangladeshs producers. On the North American markets, Mexico and Central American countries have increased their market positions over Bangladesh as a result of closer regional integration in the Americas. On the European markets, exports from Turkey and Central and Eastern European countries are competing with exports from Bangladesh. The Eastern enlargement and trade preferences for Turkey imply that the GSP (and Everything but Arms, EBA) preferences supporting Bangladesh on the EU market are losing their importance.In order to capture the latter(prenominal) issue we incorporated the enlargement of the EU as well as zero-tariff access to the EU for Turkish producers in our simulation. Table 5 The MFA abolition experiment (1) (2) (3) (4) Average export Export volumes Share world export Share world export impairment volumes 1997 volumes post-MFA Bangladesh -7% 0% 2% 2% China (incl.HongKong) -11% 60% 24% 33% India -21% 267% 3% 10% High-income Asia -1% -28% 5% 3% Other Asia -6% 1% 10% 9% Mexico & Central America -4% -42% 7% 3% Turkey 1% 40% 3% 4% Central and Eastern Europe 1% 70% 5% 7% Table 5 summarizes the effects of a MFA phase out on the RMG world market. Obviously, the highly quota constrained exporters from India and China are able to dramatically expand their exports. In the case of China, the model predicts a 60% increase in export volumes. However, exporters now face a price that is on average 11% cut down. 2 For India the picture is even more impressive, as exports are simulated t o expand by more than 260%, albeit at 20% lower prices. Bangladesh is simulated to maintain its export volumes, but would face a 7% lower price.Columns (3) and (4) in the table compare current world market shares in RMG with post-MFA shares. Clearly, China and India are increasing their world market shares. Table 6 MFA phase out Effects on main markets, change in export volumes by source and destination (percentage change relative to base 1997) ( from ( to USA Canada EU of which EU preference effect Bangladesh -21 -33 26 -12 China (incl.HongKong) 199 194 67 -19 India 752 632 80 -19 High-income Asia -51 -59 -30 -12 Other Asia -13 -25 23 -16 Mexico & Central America -44 -50 15 -16 Turkey -45 -53 72 96 Central and Eastern Europe -43 -51 81 106 Table 6 focuses on the main export markets.Obviously, Bangladesh is losing ground in North American markets, where China and India are out-competing all other suppliers, including Mexico and Central America. Only on the European mar ket does Bangladesh have validating growth rates. The granting of preferences to suppliers from CEEC countries and from Turkey enables those regions to double their sales volumes to the EU, which leads to a diversion of imports from all other sources. Experiment 2 LOWER TEXTILE TARIFFS IN BANGLADESH. The phase-out of the MFA is an orthogonal event that Bangladesh producers and policymakers will have to deal with in some way, but on which they have little influence.In contrast, there are also a number of national policy instruments available that Bangladesh could use to further its RMG industry. One of these instruments is the lowering of import taxes on textiles. It has been seen in section 2 that import barriers on textiles a vital input in RMG are relatively high in Bangladesh. The tariffs lead to an average increase of the price of imported textiles by about 30%. Clearly, a lower tariff would reduce the cost of imported textiles to the Bangladesh RMG industry, and this will d ecrease production be in the RMG sector. Table 7 reports the effects on RMG and textiles produce in case of a one-sided 20% lowering of all import tariffs on textiles (i. e. rom average 29% to average 23%, but with variation according to source region). Table 7 Output changes in Bangladesh, percent changes relative to base MFA phase out lower textile tariffs MFA phase out + lower textile tariffs Fibres 5. 1 -0. 8 4. 3 Textiles 6. 6 -0. 7 6. 0 Wearing apparel 0. 2 7. 3 7. 6 Table 8 Decomposition of export growth effects Indicator import price textiles -4. 5% price domestic textiles -0. 2% share of imports 0. 3% composite price textiles -1. 5% average price other inputs 0. 5% cost share textiles 0. 7% supply price RMG -0. 9% elasticity of substitution domestic/foreign WAP at the importer side 8. 8 change in exports 7. 9% While expansion of RMG production and exports under the MFA phase-out is rather limited, the unilateral reduction of textile import tariffs has storied positive effects on output and trade. In fact, the 20% tariff cut results in a simulated RMG output growth of more than 7%. Not surprisingly, this output effect turns out to be in the first place export driven.The lower price for imported textiles in the wake of the tariff reduction drives down the price for textiles that the RMG industry in Bangladesh uses. Table 8 summarizes the important effects. The 4. 5% lower price for imported textiles is combined with a very slight drop of domestic textile prices to yield a drop of the composite textiles price by -1. 5%. Given the large 70% cost share of textiles in RMG production, the supply price of RMG products can drop by -0. 9%. This drop is sufficient to lead importers to switch towards Bangladesh RMG products. The GTAP model has an Armington import structure with an elasticity of substitution between domestic and foreign RMG varieties equal to 8. for all importers such that the substitution effect altogether results i n an almost 8% rise of Bangladesh RMG exports. Since Bangladesh is a small doer on global RMG markets (market share around 1%), global import levels are not affected by Bangladeshs cheaper supplies. The conclusion from this course session is that lowering tariffs on textile imports does indeed boost the competitiveness of the Bangladesh RMG industry. At the said(prenominal) time, the domestic textiles industry experiences some competition from abroad, resulting in lower domestic textile prices and a slight drop in output, but this is more than compensated by increased export earnings in the RMG industry. Figure 4 Welfare effects (equivalent variation, million 1997 US$) picThe equivalent variation upbeat indicator in Figure 4 provides a summary of effects on the total economy. According to this welfare measure, the main beneficiary of the MFA phase-out is the USA. The importing regions Canada and the EU also benefit, as do India, China and Central and Eastern Europe and Turkey. T he latter two regions mainly due to the EU-preference effect. This picture makes clear why not all countries always support the abolition of the MFA. For Bangladesh a slight negative welfare effect of the MFA phase can be observed. The unilateral reduction of textiles tariffs somewhat improves this outcome, but is meagre to tip the balance. Table 9 Welfare analysis allocative and terms-of-trade effects, million US$ MFA phase out MFA phase out and lower Bangladesh textile tariffs allocative terms-of-trade allocative effectsterms-of-trade effects effects effects Bangladesh -11 -180 52 -338 China 3108 -4676 3107 -2715 India 2063 -1806 2061 -393 High-income Asia -131 -168 -131 -501 Other Asia 74 -853 73 -1348 USA 1765 6350 1767 5127 Canada 421 423 422 390 Mexico & Central America -211 -217 -211 -1178 European Union 707 50 716 16 Turkey 163 72 162 659 Central and Eastern Europe 438 96 437 1286 ROW -387 -62 -387 -981 Table 9 explains the reason for this negative outc ome. The terms of trade for Bangladesh and indeed for all the quota-restricted exporters are negatively affected as world prices for garments drop. In contrast to, for example, India, the terms-of trade loss is not compensated by allocative gains in Bangladesh. Closer inspection of the underlying data shows that the negative allocative result in the MFA phase-out scenario is mainly due to the expansion of the domestic textiles industry which is currently subsidized.Expansion of a subsidized activity receives a negative welfare evaluation, because it pulls resources into an activity that could be more effectively used elsewhere in the economy. With lower textiles tariffs, the domestic textiles industry shrinks somewhat and the negative allocative effect is dour in to an allocative gain, as less subsidization is required. CONCLUSIONS The phase out of the MFA changes global patterns of trade. India and China are the biggest winners in terms of output and export growth. In terms of w elfare, the importing countries gain most, as the import prices drop. At the same time, this means terms of trade loss for exporters. Bangladesh can only mildly benefit from the MFA phase-out, and loses ground on North American markets.Since the EU grants preferences to CEECs and Turkey, Bangladesh exporters face increasing competition on the EU market. On balance output volumes are expected to be unchanged from Bangladesh, implying a drop in market share in the expanding RMG market. A counteracting policy option for Bangladesh is the unilateral lowering of import tariffs on textiles. This reduces costs to the RMG industry and improves exports through lower supply prices. Macro-economically, increased export revenues easily compensate the loss in tariff revenues. Reference Source Office of Textiles and Apparel, United States Department of Commerce. Abbreviations MMF celluloid fibre S/V silk and vegetable MB man and male child WG woman and girl. 1
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment